Skip to main content
Normal View

JOINT COMMITTEE ON EUROPEAN UNION AFFAIRS (Sub-Committee on the Referendum on the Intergovernmental Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union) debate -
Thursday, 26 Apr 2012

Views on the Treaty from Across the European Union (Resumed)

Deputy Durkan took the Chair.

The sub-committee is resuming in public session and the usual notice in respect of mobile phones applies. This is session two, module 1, Views on the Treaty from across the European Union, from 11.30 a.m. to 1 p.m., and we are slightly behind.

I welcome everyone to today's session of the Sub-Committee on the Referendum on the Intergovernmental Treaty on Stability, Co-ordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union. This session is to focus on the views on the treaty from across the European Union. I am delighted to welcome to the sub-committee the Swedish MP, Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt.

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

I thank the Acting Chairman.

Mr. Sjöstedt is the current chairman of the Swedish Left Party and a member of the Swedish Parliament since 2010. Previously, he represented Sweden as a Member of the European Parliament and I think we met at meetings there.

I wish to advise members that Mr. Elmar Brok, MEP, was also invited to attend, but he was not able to be in attendance this morning as he had a prior engagement in Germany. He has written to the committee providing an outline of his views and he will submit a written submission to the committee next week.

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

I thank the Acting Chairman for his kind welcome and thank the sub-committee for the invitation. My name is Jonas Sjöstedt and as mentioned, I am chair of the Swedish Left Party. I was a Member of the European Parliament for 11 years and now I am in the Swedish Parliament.

I congratulate the Parliament for holding this referendum. It is a democratic example in Europe that the Parliament lets people decide and has an open democratic debate on a vital issue such as this one.

I was very active in the referendum on the euro in Sweden in 2003 in which, as the sub-committee may be aware, Sweden voted "No". We did not join the euro which gives us a slightly different position in this situation. We have been able to use our interest rate and our exchange rate in order to protect our economy from the crisis. It made our situation, if not good, at least better than it would have been in the eurozone. We also are able to borrow money from the market at a lower cost and to do that, we have our own central bank, the Riksbanken.

Sweden went through a deep economic crisis in the 1990s. We had banks that went bankrupt and experienced a large fall in exports. We got through the crisis partly because we were quite tough on our banks. We did not pay their debts. We nationalised the banks that did not make it and sold them later at a price higher than that at which we bought them. That is a vital lesson. One of the reasons Sweden is doing better and that we do not have these big losses in the banking system is that we were quite tough on them last time and they learned from that.

We also have stability in the public finances. We have a debt level of 30% at present, and it is decreasing. There is a kind of political consensus that we should keep public finances in strict order.

On the treaty and the European crisis, to be able to see what cure one needs for an illness, one needs first to know what caused the illness. The main causes of the euro crisis vary from country to country and one must be open to that, but one cannot deny that the losses in the banking sector, and the big risk-taking in financial speculation, is one of the major causes, and Ireland knows all about that.

A second matter that plays a vital role, especially in the southern European countries, is the loss of competitiveness, and that they can no longer compete on the global market and they import far more than they export. Both of these problems are connected to the euro because the low interest rate with the euro boosted the lending and the risk-taking of the banking system and being stuck in the euro has been one major explanation for the bad competitiveness position in the countries.

In most countries, the deficits and the economic problems with the national budgets come from the crisis. It is not the reason for the crisis but it is an effect of the crisis. If one wants to cure the illness, one must address more problems than the lack of balance in budgets and public deficits. That is vital. If one does not do that, one risks going even deeper into crisis and not being able to cure the reasons for it. That is where Europe stands now.

Europe is on the brink of a very serious recession, which is already there in southern Europe but also in countries such as the Netherlands. There is a risk that too much austerity will deepen the recession in many countries, will make the economic problems more severe and will make it more difficult for countries to recover. That is why it might be a mistake to have very rigid systems for national budgets in a situation where the economy needs not only balance, but also investment.

If I look back on the crisis in the Swedish economy in the 1990s, for a couple of years we ran deficits which were far larger than those that are allowed in this package but we came back because we also invested our way out of the crisis. That would not have been possible with this treaty. It is hard to predict the development in Europe and it is hard to say that one size fits all when it comes to the budget policy for the foreseeable future. This treaty is dominated by a rigid way of thinking.

The present euro policy has two main aims: to save the euro as a currency, and to save the financial system and the banking system. The price is paid by those in the member states who suffer under cuts, and also the countries are obliged to enforce privatisations. One can see this clear priority in the European Central Bank that gives enormous loans to the banking system with an interest rate of 1% but is not helping the countries in a similar way. If one reverses that, the situation would be quite different in Europe. Perhaps arrangements like that should play a larger role in seeking to resolve the difficulties than adopting pacts like this one.

If we wish to cure the causes of the crisis, we must look deeply into issues of financial regulation with a view to making it impossible for the banks to make the same mistakes ever again. The problem is that if one pays all the debts of the banks and does not hold their owners responsible, they will most likely learn the lesson that there is no risk for them in any circumstance and will engage in the same activities once again. That is why it is vital bankers are forced to take full responsibility for the mistakes they make in their business transactions. It is also obvious that at least in the case of Greece and Portugal there will be a need sooner or later to write down the debt. There is no way around that when one considers how the situation is evolving. The difficulty is when one transfers the debt from private to public, one is, with open eyes, transferring to the public the cost of mistakes that are partly due to private investors.

The fiscal compact or euro compact, whatever one calls it, is in a very unclear situation. It is not obvious it will become reality. Looking at the situation in France, for example, the probable new President, Mr. Hollande, has stated his desire for the compact to be renegotiated. We have a situation in the Netherlands, with an election to take place, where the ratification of the treaty has been postponed. There may well be a new parliamentary majority in that country following the election which is far more critical of the treaty than the current majority. The future is not as certain as it might look in many countries.

Sweden, even though we are not in the eurozone, has a right-wing Government which has said it will sign up to the pact. The main argument for my country ratifying the treaty is that we are not obliged to follow the rules in it. This seems to me a peculiar argument for signing up to anything. The Swedish Government and the Social Democratic Workers Party have both expressed the view that if we were obliged to follow the content of the pact, we would not sign it because we do not need it and do not see the point in it. The decision to ratify is, in my view, more a sign of loyalty to the European Union system than anything to do with the economy.

What will the consequences be if the pact goes through and the European Union is able to enforce it in member states? First, and it is the greatest risk attached to the treaty, it will deepen the recession. If one has a very severe austerity policy in a situation where the economy is already going down, one risks making what is bad worse, with a shrinking economy and an increase in the volume of debt in regard to GDP. Second, it will not be possible for member states to adapt national economic policy to their particular situation. This runs the risk of strengthening existing negative trends in an economy by requiring greater reductions in expenditure. There might be a little room to manoeuvre when the economy is doing better and there is a surplus. However, that is probably the wrong way to do it and one should do it the other way around if one wants a more stable economic policy. The pact has severe consequences for member states' ability to formulate their own national economic policy. The third aspect to consider is that the treaty has implications for democracy in that it transfers massive powers to the European Commission and the European Court of Justice and gives a strong mandate in respect of supranational economic policy to representatives who are not democratically elected and cannot be unseated in a democratic election. That is a principal factor in itself. It also makes it much more difficult for the Irish people or any other people to choose a different direction in the future if they so wish, as is the right of representative parliaments in any democracy to do.

My last argument for why the treaty is not a very good one is that it simply will not work. It is obvious that many member states will not implement it and that it will probably break down quite soon. In short, it will not function but it might well do some harm on the way to that point. We will probably see more packages like it in the future but as they cannot not solve the causes of the crisis, I cannot see how this or any similar pact will function.

Deputy Dominic Hannigan took the Chair.

I thank Mr. Sjöstedt for his statement

I welcome Mr. Sjöstedt and thank him for this contribution. He observed at the outset that being from Sweden, which is outside the euro, he might have a different perspective on the issues. We are faced with an economic crisis in the eurozone which requires a eurozone-wide solution. I read a newspaper article at the weekend in which the observation was noted - I do not recall to whom it was attributed - that every government knows what we need to do to get us out of this situation but nobody knows how to get re-elected afterwards. We have seen shifts in Spain and Britain from the left to the right, while France may possibly be moving in the other direction. All sides of the equation are coming up with the arguments and voters on all side are rejecting them. It is clear that austerity is affecting many different people in many different ways.

In that context, the treaty proposes to enforce rules of good fiscal management which will ensure governments, whether on the left or the right, retain the ability to increase spending, cut services or whatever within the confines of the rules. Notwithstanding the budgetary restraints imposed by the treaty, each democratically elected government will judge for itself how much it wishes to cut and how much to spend. The rules set out in the treaty will be good for Europe in terms of enforcing stability while accepting there will be different priorities within individual countries. With respect to the arguments put forth by Mr. Sjöstedt, putting in force these guidelines will improve the stability of the eurozone, enhance the likelihood of recovery and facilitate inward investment, especially in this country. We have heard diverse views from delegates from various countries, but on the whole, the majority of people who appear before the sub-committee acknowledge the difficulties we are facing and, in that context, accept the rationale of ratification.

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

The reaction across Europe against governments which enforce these policies has many causes. One of the major reasons people react so strongly against government, whether right wing or left wing, is that they see that the European Union is paying for the mistakes of the banks and all the burden has been imposed on the common people. If a government is to secure public acceptance for its policies, there must be a balance of responsibility. If people see those who created the crisis are paying at least some of the price for it, they will be more willing to carry some of the burden themselves. If people see there is a way out, that investment is also being made and there is a just, defensible economic policy, they will be more willing to accept the need for belt tightening. The problem is there is nothing like that in this treaty. There is no reference to investment or financial regulation. In fact, the decision made at the summit at which the pact was proposed declared the banks should carry no losses where debt is being written down. This imbalance is very provoking to people throughout Europe. One must consider the treaty in that context.

I fully agree that in the long run there is no other way than to ensure member states have sound finances. It is not possible to borrow one's way out of a crisis and economic stability is essential. Sweden suffered a severe economic crisis in the 1990s from which it took years to recover and to reduce our deficit. I am convinced, however, that if we had cut back to the extent required under this treaty, greater harm would have been done to the economy. One must accept that coming back to growth, investment and development sometimes takes time and sometimes takes deficits. While one must of course get them under control, cuts without investment will meet with little public acceptance. This is the weakness underlying the present European policy. One of course can put the responsibility on the European level by stating one is obliged to take such measures according to Brussels. However, by going too far in so doing, one risks harming European co-operation in itself. I can discern this happening around Europe at present. People are changing their views on Europe because they see their politicians blaming Europe for the policies they are obliged to enforce. This is a risky game.

I thank Mr. Sjöstedt for his attendance and for taking the time to make a presentation and to take some questions and answers. The work of the sub-committee is drawing to a close but I understand that tomorrow morning, it will be addressed by the president of SIPTU, the largest trade union in the State. This has been a wide-ranging and useful range of debate and discussions, with many voices being heard from Ireland and Europe. Mr. Sjöstedt referred to the changing dynamic in Europe, given the Dutch Government has collapsed and it appears as though France will have a new President. I of course do not wish to pre-empt the decision of the French people but the indications are that a new President will be elected who is clear on the need for a new plan for growth. One cannot have austerity on its own and there must be a real plan with real investment. Consequently, it appears as though the tide is beginning to turn and I seek more of Mr. Sjöstedt's thoughts in this regard.

I read a report filed yesterday by the BBC's European editor who has a sense that austerity was all fine when it affected the periphery and when it related to penance for those countries' supposed financial recklessness - I refer to the narrative Merkel has given to the German people in particular. However, now when the implications of such a policy begin to hit the core states, there appears to be a significant change of direction. I seek Mr. Sjöstedt's thoughts in this regard. I noted with interest his point that although the Swedish Government supports this policy, it would never implement such policies itself in Sweden. The entire premise of the European Union was supposed to be based on solidarity and on acting in a fair and just way. There is no easy solution for Ireland or any country but there are choices on how one deals with this problem. I seek an insight into what is happening in Sweden and on what are the Swedish people's views on the changing dynamics over the last one or two weeks in particular.

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

There is an interesting debate under way among economists in Europe, the United States and other parts of the world in which many economists are questioning the manner in which Europe is handling the crisis, as well as the one-sided approach of going down the road of austerity and privatisation. It is suggested that doing so will not break the circle in which we find ourselves. I believe one can see this happening right now in Europe, whereby we have tried such policies for a couple of years and they are not working very well. Greece now is in its fifth year of recession and countries that go through such an experience change fundamentally. In addition, one harms the real economy and real production in such countries and there also must be investment to be able to emerge from the crisis.

The European Union has tools in this regard. For example, the European Investment Bank could play a more active role and the European Central Bank could adopt a different policy in respect of helping countries more than helping banks. Europe has different directions in which it could go and the political shift that now is evident in both the Netherlands and France is a sign that throughout Europe, politicians are thinking that another way out of this crisis must be found. At the same time, it is necessary to return to budgetary balance in the long run but it will take some time for Europe to do this. If we step on the brake while going uphill, it will take a longer time than it would in the other case.

I believe a major political shift now is evident in many of the more powerful European countries. The recession is now something that is not merely hitting the south of Europe. It is hitting the Netherlands and a risky situation has emerged in France. Were a bailout for Spain to take place, which looks increasingly likely, France could be the next country to be hit by the crisis. Thus far, one way has been tried and it has not been working very well. Consequently, it is time to look for something more balanced in our approach. One can make comparisons with the United States. While one can state the United States is right wing, when it comes to economic policy and the manner in which the Federal Reserve works, it is more progressive and open-minded than Europe in its handling of this crisis.

I welcome Mr. Sjöstedt before the sub-committee and thank him for his participation. I wish to respond to some of his points and to ask a few related questions. The challenge in balancing budgets or in achieving budgetary stability is quite similar to that identified by St. Augustine in the context of being virtuous when he stated, "Lord make me virtuous, but not quite yet". It always is something that will happen down the road. I emphasise that in many cases, this is legitimate and I do not suggest it is being pushed down the road for reasons of political self-interest. I acknowledge there is a good time and a bad time to do stuff like this. Nonetheless, it is understandable for people who are looking in at what is happening within the eurozone to draw the conclusion that the budgetary stability commitments that are being made will not be delivered. The reason they draw such a conclusion is such commitments have not been delivered in the past and there is no reason for them to expect otherwise. In this context, does it provide further background for the reasons the stability treaty is being introduced in the sense it seeks to provide additional credibility to such commitments?

The second point I put to Mr. Sjöstedt is the kind of analysis he would put forward, which is perfectly legitimate, is that the stability treaty is causing the difficulty in which we find ourselves or rather, the current direction of European policymakers is causing the difficulty in which we find ourselves. However, I question such an analysis. Is it not the case the reason many countries are in such difficulty is that the financial markets will not lend to them? That Ireland is in this terrible horizon of difficulty at present is not because of the stability treaty but because no one will lend to us and we are in a programme. Moreover the bond yields for Spain and Italy have risen is not because the stability treaty is on the horizon but because people have a concern that were they to lend money to those countries, they would not get it back at the rate at which they lent it. As I was greatly struck by Mr. Sjöstedt's analysis, I ask him to comment on the point that what we could be doing here is attributing responsibility to the symptom, rather than to the cause. I suggest the cause in this regard was the unwillingness of people to lend to sovereign states.

I will conclude with Mr. Sjöstedt's point regarding the role of the banks in all this. I can comment most knowledgeably in respect of Ireland. While he stated the banks caused the difficulties, in the example of Ireland, banks and the lending thereof fuelled an asset and credit boom due to extremely weak - in fact non-existent - regulation. Thereafter, however, the Government of the day decided to make spending and taxation decisions on the basis of that credit boom in the sense that it banked temporary tax receipts and funded permanent spending programmes. The banks did not force the Government of the day to do that. They enabled its action but it was the Government elected by the people which made the relevant decisions.

I would be interested in Mr. Sjöstedt's comments on the narrative which states that everything is the fault of the banks. Ireland will have a deficit of €16 billion this year. There is no doubt but that the banks played a role in the creation of this. Unfortunately, those who made certain political decisions also played a major role. The people were told, completely understandably, that if they voted for particular parties, then X would happen. They voted for these parties and no fault is due to them in this regard. When the relevant Governments came to power, however, they stated that the money accruing to the Exchequer was going to last for ever and they proceed to spend accordingly. How would Mr. Sjöstedt evaluate the narrative in this regard?

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

I think banks - as the case with other companies - must bear responsibility for their actions. If a farmer or local shop owner makes a bad decision and if his or her business goes bust or he or she defaults on a debt, it is his or her responsibility. That is the way the market economy works. Basically, the same should apply in respect of banks and the owners must take full responsibility for the business they are doing. If this is not the case, the situation is made worse because there are greater risks involved. Politicians can, of course, make things either better or worse. I admit that sometimes they make matters worse. Other times, however, we have more wisdom.

Apart from the way the taxation system or the housing market are organised, there is also the question of the interest rate. One of the major weaknesses of the euro is that it is not possible to adapt the interest rate to the economy. The other tools available will not provide as quick a solution as using the interest rate. That is a historical lesson for the eurozone countries to learn. There are, of course, many explanations. As already stated, one of the main problems is that austerity is being used to pay for the banks. That is what makes it so difficult for people to accept.

Why does the market not provide loans? One major reason is that they may expect not to get their money back from Greece and Portugal. If one compares countries with high levels of debt with each other, one discovers something interesting. The countries which have their own central banks, namely, Japan, the US and even the United Kingdom, tend to pay interest rates which are a great deal lower than those paid by countries in the eurozone which have either the same or lower levels of debt but which do not have their own central banks. Why is this? It is because central banks work as a lender of last resort and guarantee the currency. This also goes for Sweden. We sometimes pay less than 1% when we obtain loans on the international markets. There is a major weakness in the euro system in this regard and this must be changed in the future. In other words, the role of the European Central Bank must be changed. For indebted countries, this will be far more important than anything else.

The debt levels of Portugal and Greece are so high that one takes a risk by giving them loans. However, the structure of the euro and the way the European Central Bank works must also be taken into consideration in this regard. Therefore, a number of different solutions must be found. It will be many years before the southern European countries will be able to borrow on the markets. However, things look better for Ireland in this respect. The question that arises in this regard is how to regain credibility in order to obtain loans on the open market through the bond system. All of the countries involved here have been obliged to make exceptional cuts to budgets and to implement incredible austerity policies. It is difficult to imagine their experiencing anything worse and not making any headway. Why is that? It is because the budget consists of two parts, namely, income and expenditure. It is possible to cut expenditure but if one stops activity in the economy, one will reduce one's income. That is what is happening in southern Europe, where tax revenues are diminishing. One must have the two parts to which I refer in order to find a solution.

I wish to make it clear that I do not deny that the crisis countries will be obliged to be extremely strict in respect of their expenditure for many years to come. They will be obliged to identify many priorities and to make sacrifices. If one does not approach this matter in the context of investment, growth and bringing income into the economy, then one will not make it. One can cut back as much as one likes but one will still not make it. Greece and Portugal are in that situation now. If they do not attract either a stimulus or new investment, the day will come when they will no longer be able to pay. The sooner a country adopts policies which take cognisance of the income and expenditure elements to which I refer, the greater are its prospects of extricating itself from its crisis. The problem with the intergovernmental treaty is that it is extremely one-sided in nature and lacks the flexibility required in a crisis such as that currently being experienced.

One matter which appears to be vital in the context of the debate in Ireland is the recital in the ESM treaty to the effect that a country's ability to obtain loans under this mechanism will depend on whether it has signed up to the fiscal compact. I was a Member of the European Parliament for 11 years and I spent many late evenings in the building where the Council meets negotiating, in conciliation procedures, new laws for Europe. I am aware, therefore, that something which is contained in the recital is not mandatory. If one wants adherence to the legislation, then one places what one is seeking to do in the paragraphs. There is a difference between the recitals and what is actually contained in the treaty. That is most important.

No country that finds itself in a particular situation will be obliged to go to the stability mechanism in order to obtain loans. For example, Spain, Portugal and Greece - which will, for sure, be there again - will be in the situation to fulfil the demands set down in the treaty in any event. They will actually be way beyond that in terms of their economic situations. I do not really see the validity of the argument in respect of this recital to be honest.

I welcome our guest and thank him for coming before the sub-committee. It is quite some time since I first attended meetings of sub-committees of the European Parliament. At such meetings, Members of Parliament from all over Europe all offered different remedies at different times in respect of different situations. Different remedies are applicable in this instance because not all of the same circumstances apply. When Sweden underwent its economic difficulties, the crisis it experienced was triggered by the collapse of the former Soviet Union and other matters. Sweden's immediate trading neighbours encountered similar difficulties. In the current instance, the banking crisis is affecting virtually every country in the EU but it is particularly affecting the eurozone states. The banking crisis to which I refer is also being experienced in the United States. In addition to this problem with banking, individual member states of the EU are experiencing their own individual crises. In Ireland's case, the crisis was caused by bad regulation, non-adherence to good practice and overindulgence in a splurge on property. The crises in Spain and Portugal were caused in the same way.

We are of the view that our situation is slightly different to that in which Sweden previously found itself. However, Mr. Sjöstedt said something interesting, namely, that countries in difficulty must be extremely careful with regard to how they spend their money in the future. Deputy Mac Lochlainn stated that the tide is turning. The tide in respect of economic recovery is turning very slowly but in order to facilitate what is happening in this regard we must put in place good, sound economic principles. That is what we have done in Ireland. We have selected the growth areas, namely, the export sector which comprises the areas of IT, pharmaceuticals, chemicals and agrifood and which are doing well. These are not doing tremendously well but in comparison to other areas they are doing very well.

What we are trying to do is decide what would be the best message to communicate to outside investors in order to encourage them to create employment here. Would it better to go easy and postpone any fundamental economic recovery tactics to ensure future investment in the economy? Would investors have a second look and feel the Irish people are not serious? I remind all present of the Greek situation. What is the answer for those member states that are in difficulty? Is it to claim we do not wish to pay or we are incapable of paying our debts? In that case, international confidence in the ability of those economies to survive will be shattered. This in turn will result in a prolongation of austerity.

Mr. Sjöstedt said there must be a curtailment of spending if one wants to work one's way out of a financial crisis. Austerity itself is not the end; it is a means to the end. Otherwise, one continues spending which does not improve the financial position and one gets into a worse position leading to lack of trading and investment.

Mr. Sjöstedt said if a bank is malfunctioning it should be allowed to collapse, a view which I agreed with some time back. Unfortunately, the experience of the United States does not prove that. The collapse of Lehman Brothers had a knock-on effect on the rest of the banking system. A similar situation arose in the UK with a feared domino effect with the run on Northern Rock, forcing the British Government to move to address the issue. In the case of Ireland, Anglo Irish Bank was, unfortunately, not a small bank but a very large one. It grew over a period with billions of euro at stake. Its collapse would have a serious impact on the wider Irish banking system. The then Government had to move across the board to protect deposits.

I believe we are on the right course. In the past, we tried spending our way out of a recession but it did not work. We must now go a different route in putting our economic fundamentals in order first and then talking about investment.

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

I agree with Deputy Durkan that countries are different from each other and he knows the Irish situation far better than I do. However, realising that countries are different from each other should give rise to thoughts about the strict common policies in various fields. Different economic structures need different economic policies. That is one of the hard lessons from the euro experience. Many people in the European Union thought with the single currency there would be similar economic development across the eurozone. In fact, it was the opposite. If the single currency did not suit some countries very well, should the common budget policy and its one-size-fits-all approach suit all countries too? That is what this treaty will do. One must be able to adapt to one's national circumstances. If not, one can get into more severe trouble. That for me is an argument against rigid treaties like this one.

When we had the referendum on the euro in Sweden, we heard many arguments similar to the Deputy's. It was argued that if we entered the single currency, we would put ourselves under strict regulation, strict demands for deficits to adapt to the single currency policy which would give credibility to Swedish economic policy while providing stability and low interest rates. These were the main arguments. There was a bit of scaremongering too before the vote with some claiming if we did not vote "Yes" we would get into serious trouble with capital flowing out of the country the morning after. It never happened. It turned out the other way around.

Our ability to adapt to our national economic development means sometimes we have higher interest rates and other times, lower. The exchange rate goes up and down depending on the economy's strength. That is good for the Swedish economy. One can never buy credibility by signing a treaty. One can only do so by conducting a trustworthy economic policy. There is no shortcut. If Ireland signs up to this treaty, it will have exactly the same trouble going back to the market which will check how the Irish economy is doing. Accordingly, I am reluctant to accept the Deputy's argument.

If the main problem is lack of growth and investment, one must have the room to manoeuvre to have an economic policy. That is where the problem with this treaty comes in as I see it.

Where do we get the resources to do exactly that? Mr. Sjöstedt is talking about reflation which means borrowing. From where does Ireland borrow?

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

I have a different view than many in the Irish debate. The single currency in itself is a mistake. One must open a door for countries which want to leave the single currency.

That is a different issue.

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

No, it is not. It has to do with competitiveness. Currencies are deeply connected to competitiveness. I imagine that will not be the choice of the Irish people, so other ways have to be found.

If one cuts back too hard and has too severe an austerity policy, one will do more harm to the economy. One must have a certain flexibility in that regard.

What is the right level of cutbacks?

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

That depends on one's economic development. If one is in a recession and one cuts back very hard, then the recession is made worse with less tax revenues. The cuts must adapt to the national budget. One cannot rely on a treaty like this and claim it will solve the country's economic problems because it will not. Ireland has to solve the problem itself. That is the responsibility of the Irish Parliament and Government.

Being aware of the differences between Sweden and Ireland, when Sweden had its deep economic crisis in the 1990s, if this treaty had been introduced then we would not have been able to save our welfare state. We managed to regain our competitiveness and strength in the economy by introducing very painful cuts in the social security sector which we had to do-----

What percentage of cuts were introduced?

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

We had a deficit one year of 16% which was disastrous. However, we did not have to pay as much for the banks as Ireland did. We had a recession for three consecutive years doing so. Once we got our economy back on track-----

What is meant by painful welfare cuts? Was it 2%

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

We lowered unemployment benefits by 20%. We cut back on municipalities with approximately 100,000 laid off in the public sector.

Was it less than 10%?

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

Yes, it was less than 10%. I apologise for not having specific figures.

It is just to give us an idea.

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

We regained our competitiveness and came back to pay our debts. We went from being 80% in debt to 30%. There was a national consensus from the left to the right that Sweden should pay back its debts but when the economy was back strong.

We know about that and have thought about it in this country as well. We pondered introducing all the cuts in areas like social welfare up-front but felt that the impact would have been disastrous for the economy. A judgment call had to be made. In Sweden, the bulk of the cuts were introduced up-front and they had maximum impact. Has the country got back to where the economy was before? We have received economic information over the past number of years with economists telling us the trend is in such a direction, and we may have gained or lost 1% or 2%. Relating that to the period before the recession, to what extent has Sweden recovered ground? It became competitive, as Ireland is doing now. We are much more competitive than we were four or five years ago. We are on the road. The Swedish economy became more competitive as a result of a harsh lesson but to what extent has the country recovered in terms of economic strength and security?

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

We are much stronger now than we were in the 1990s. Ireland must act in a more painful way, with internal devaluation through lowering social benefits, etc. We had a floating exchange rate, which helps a lot in such a position, particularly with regard to the export industry. We went from having a banking sector that took many risks to keeping it much tighter through regulation, which helped our economy. We nationalised the banks at an early stage so there was no payment to owners for the losses. That was important. To be honest, the banking sector is returning to a state which is too risky and large; it is four times our GDP in turnout.

One conclusion from the crisis is that there must be a long-term budgetary balance in the economy. It took a number of years for us to come back, and it was an export-oriented return. If we had practised the terms of this treaty at the time, we would not have been able to come back. There were a number of years when we had deficits, and that was unavoidable.

How much of a deficit did Sweden have after the crash?

Mr. Jonas Sjöstedt, MP

The debt went to approximately 80% of GDP.

If there are no further questions, I thank Mr. Sjöstedt for taking the time to come here today. It has taken at least a day of his time so we are very appreciative of him and his assistant for making the journey and telling us about Sweden's position. Our final meeting tomorrow will see Mr. Jack O'Connor of SIPTU attending and I hope to see all the members here.

The sub-committee adjourned at 12.35 p.m. until 10 a.m. on Friday, 27 April 2012.
Top
Share